Frontiers of Economics in China

ISSN 1673-3444

ISSN 1673-3568(Online)

CN 11-5744/F

邮发代号 80-978

   优先出版

合作单位

全文下载排行
一年内发表文章 | 两年内 | 三年内 | 全部 | 最近1个月下载排行 | 最近1年下载排行

当前位置: 最近1个月下载排行
Please wait a minute...
选择: 合并摘要 显示/隐藏图片
Examining the Factors Affecting Personal Income: An Empirical Study Based on Survey Data in Chinese Cities
Lihui Wang, Junyi Shen
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (4): 515-544.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0022-0
摘要   PDF (441KB)

This paper empirically analyzes the factors affecting personal income in urban China using survey data of the “Preference and Life Satisfaction Survey” conducted by the Global COE project of Osaka University from 2009 to 2013. We consider education level as an endogenous variable, and both ordinary least squares (OLS) regression and instrumental variable (IV) regression are performed. We find a number of factors, such as sex, age, education, and marriage that significantly affect personal income. In addition, differences between different occupations are also investigated.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Why the Industrial Revolution Started in 18th Century Britain, Not China, from the Perspective of Globalization
Li Zhang
Frontiers of Economics in China    2021, 16 (1): 124-169.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-013-021-0006-5
摘要   PDF (987KB)

The research examines the role of market expansion and international labor division in the British Industrial Revolution from the perspective of globalization. The research shows that British cotton textile output in pieces grew 275 times from the 1770s to the mid-1850s and documents that such growth would never have happened without a vast overseas market for the supply of raw cotton and the sale of products. The paper argues that the continuous and dramatic expansion of overseas markets allowed the British cotton industry to expand greatly without hitting the ceiling of marginal returns, leading not only to the great expansion of production, but also to technological and institutional innovations, and that international labor division made it possible for the industry to import ample amounts of raw cotton and export large amounts of cotton textiles. In contrast, foreign demand for Chinese cotton textiles increased significantly in the late 18th and early 19th centuries, but accounted for only 0.3% of production capacity, which was too little to lift the law of diminishing marginal returns and to induce either technological or institutional changes. As a result, only Smithian growths could be achieved through optimal resource utilization and specialization in production.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Research on the Education of Migrant Children in China: A Review of the Literature
Yuanyuan Chen, Shuaizhang Feng, Yujie Han
Frontiers of Economics in China    2019, 14 (2): 168-202.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-008-019-0010-7
摘要   PDF (1139KB)

With the rapid urbanization and mass internal migration in China during the past several decades, the population of children who migrate with their parents to the cities has now reached over 35 million. The education of migrant children poses significant challenges to China’s hukou based education system. In this paper, we first review the policy developments and descriptive studies related to migrant children’s education to offer a comprehensive view of the issue. We then provide in-depth examination of several important quantitative literatures, including the effect of parental migration on children’s education, schooling choices of migrant children and their impacts on school performance, peer effects of migrant children in urban public schools. Overall, although considerable progress has been made regarding migrant children’s education in China, more fundamental policy reforms are necessary to improve the quality of migrant children’s education at the compulsory education level and beyond.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Dual Circulation and China's Development
Justin Yifu Lin
Frontiers of Economics in China    2021, 16 (1): 30-34.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-013-021-0002-7
摘要   PDF (210KB)

In 2020, China proposed a new development paradigm centered on domestic circulation with a "dual circulation" model in which domestic circulation and international circulation promote each other. This new paradigm reflects a clear understanding of China's development trend that saw its share of exports in the GDP declining steadily since 2006. However, the new paradigm does not necessarily mean that China should change its past policy of fully utilizing domestic and international markets and resources in economic development. Because of large economies of scale in modern manufacturing sector, China should continue to make full use of international markets.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Product Market Competition and Innovation: What Can We Learn from Economic Theory?
Zhiqi Chen
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (3): 450-464.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0019-2
摘要   PDF (231KB)

By means of a literature review, this paper strives to provide some clarity on the much-debated relationship between product market competition and firms’ incentives to innovate. It shows that in the literature there does not exist a robust relationship between competition and incentives to innovate. Therefore, it would be futile to continue the debate over whether competition stimulates or hinders innovation. A more useful approach is to make a distinction between pre-innovation competition and post-innovation competition, as it provides a way for reconciling many of the seemingly contradictory findings from the literature. Another important insight from the literature is that the relationship between competition and innovation depends on the source of increased competition.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Inequality and Crime in China
Jiangli Zhu, Zilian Li
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (2): 309-339.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0014-7
摘要   PDF (706KB)

This paper attempts to investigate comprehensively, a “U”-shaped relationship between income inequality and crime rates in China after building a cost-benefit analysis model, by using time series data from 1981–2012 and panel data from 1999–2012. The empirical results show that: firstly, in the time series model, the U-shaped relationships between inequality and the total crime rate and rates of various crimes except from smuggling, are very significant in the period of 1981–2012, secondly, the panel threshold models show that inequality and crime tend to be correlated positively with each other during 1999–2012, because the inequality level during this period is much higher than the turning points of inequality estimated in the time series models, although three regions with different development levels are located in different parts of a U-shaped curve between inequality and crime.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Chinese Economy under the New "Dual Circulation" Strategy: Challenges and Opportunities—A Summary of the Annual SUFE Macroeconomic Report (2020–2021)
Kevin X.D. Huang, Shuangjian Li, Guoqiang Tian
Frontiers of Economics in China    2021, 16 (1): 1-29.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-013-021-0001-0
摘要   PDF (1116KB)

Entering year 2020, the Chinese economy was struck by the COVID-19 outbreak. The unprecedented pandemic, entangled with the already elevated complexities in the nation’s internal environment and external surroundings, aggravated its economic outlook. Internal factors including severe education mismatch in China’s labor force, its vanishing demographic dividend, the declined purchasing power of its middle-income groups, risen leverage ratio of households and enterprises, and soared local government debt reinforced to weaken China’s domestic demand. External factors, especially uncertainty in the China-US relation in the face of the re-shaping global value chain, dragged world economic recovery and thus China’s exports and imports. This summary report highlights some major challenges and opportunities faced by the nation under its new development strategy that stresses internal circulation of domestic economy aided by its interaction with the globe. Our analyses based on IAR-CMM model provide a unified framework for addressing China’s short-, medium-, and long-term issues in an internally coherent manner. Looking into year 2021, our benchmark projection reports an 8.4% annual real GDP growth rate. Alternative scenario analyses and policy simulations are conducted to assess the impacts of potential downside risks and the corresponding policy options for ensuring implicit targets. Through the lens of these analyses, we conclude that a refocus on effective management of internal demand, while deepening structural reforms on supply side and advancing orderly opening up, can help smooth the internal and external circulations of the Chinese economy to achieve high-quality development.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Why Does the World Need a Reserve Asset with a Hard Anchor?
Dongsheng Di, Warren Coats, Yuxuan Zhao
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (4): 545-570.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0023-7
摘要   PDF (835KB)

From the 1970s, the global currency system has two features: the use of one or a few sovereign currencies as the global reserve asset and the floating exchange rate regime between major currencies. This paper points out that the costs of the dollar’s use as an international reserve currency exceed the benefits for both the US and the rest of the world. These costs include the exporting of American manufacturing as a byproduct of its current account deficit needed to supply its currency to the rest of the world. In addition to the detriment to trade from unpredictable exchange rate fluctuations, the termination of the U.S. obligation to redeem its currency for gold also removed an important restraint on deficit financing for the US and many other countries in the short-run, thus promoting excessive leverage that was a major contributor to the 2008 financial crisis. The paper suggests replacing several main countries’ currencies in international reserves with a real Special Drawing Right (SDR) issued according to currency board rules.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
IPO Pricing Efficiency in China: A ChiNext Board Focus
Qi Deng, Zhong-guo Zhou
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (2): 280-308.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0013-0
摘要   PDF (591KB)

This paper examines what determines the offer price for a ChiNext IPO and discusses how we can improve the current “Chinese-style” bookbuilding process. We establish that the ChiNext IPO underwriter relies upon the institutional investors to discover the issuer’s intrinsic value (in the form of a preliminary price), and that the same underwriter adjusts the preliminary price to establish the final offer price, based on its assessment of the institutional investors’ motivations. Since the underwriter does not have discretionary power in new share allocation, this “Chinese-style” bookbuilding process contains certain pitfalls from an information asymmetry standpoint. The institutional investors mainly use “simple and direct” variables that do not adequately reflect the issuer’s true intrinsic value to develop the preliminary price, while the underwriter adjusts that price downward to establish the offer price to clear the market, as a measure to counter a perceived free-rider issue among the institutional investors. This process, in effect, contributes to initial IPO underpricing and causes principal-agent conflicts between the underwriter and the issuer. We argue that such a pricing inefficiency could be improved by an innovative “bookbuilding plus price discretionary auction” process, which is a combination of the modified OpenIPO and Taiwan-style auctioned IPO approaches.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
China's Growth Slowdown: Labor Supply, Productivity, or What?
Anping Chen, Nicolaas Groenewold
Frontiers of Economics in China    2021, 16 (1): 35-66.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-013-021-0003-4
摘要   PDF (1205KB)

There has been much discussion of the sources of China’s growth slowdown but little formal econometric analysis of this question. Chen and Groenewold (2019) show that the slowdown was primarily supply-driven, but they stopped short of identifying specific supply variables. This paper extends their analysis and distinguishes several potential supply components: labor supply, productivity, and capital accumulation. Our results confirm their main conclusion that supply dominates the explanation of the slowdown. A model with two supply factors (labor supply and productivity) reveals that both components contribute to the slowdown, although productivity makes the greater contribution. However, when capital stock is added to the model, the decline in the capital accumulation rate becomes an important factor in the growth slowdown, to some extent replacing the effects of both labor supply and productivity.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Digital Economy, Entrepreneurship, and High-Quality Economic Development: Empirical Evidence from Urban China
ZHAO Tao, ZHANG Zhi, LIANG Shangkun
Frontiers of Economics in China    2022, 17 (3): 393-426.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-015-022-0015-6
摘要   PDF (1023KB)

The paper discusses the effects of the digital economy on high-quality urban development and its mechanism. Theoretically, the digital economy can empower high-quality development by boosting entrepreneurial vitality. Empirically, the paper measures the overall level of the digital economy and high-quality development of the 222 Chinese cities at and above the prefecture level during 2011–2016, depicts the entrepreneurial vitality of the cities with the microscopic data of the business registration information and makes quantitative analysis on this basis. The result shows: Digital economy has remarkably improved high-quality development and this conclusion still exists after the robustness test selecting historical data as the instrumental variables and the Broadband China pilot policy as the quasi experiment. The analysis of the mechanism of action indicates that encouraging public entrepreneurship is an important mechanism of the digital economy to release the dividend of high quality development. Finally, thanks to the threshold model and the spatial model, it is found that the positive effect of the digital economy has the characteristics of nonlinear increment and spatial spillover of the “marginal effects.” The research of the paper stimulates the reasons for high-quality development and the understanding of the effects, mechanisms and regional differences of high-quality development empowered by the digital economy.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
The Spread of Western Economics in China: Features and Influence (1840–1949)
Lin Cheng, Shen Zhang
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (2): 193-227.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0010-9
摘要   PDF (1345KB)

The spread of Western economics in modern China is a content-rich historical event which has taken more than a century. A complete understanding of this event depends on the analysis and summary of its features. This paper suggests that the spread of Western economics in modern China exhibits five main features: openness, periodicity, applicability, localization and limitation. Openness reflects the active attitude of Chinese scholars to learning and propagating Western economics. Periodicity reflects the changes in its effectiveness and focus over time. Applicability reflects its goal of promoting the development of Chinese economics and providing policy applications for China’s economic growth. Localization of Western economic theories in China follows the trend of selected introduction and modification according to local situations. And limitation is inevitable because of the many difficulties facing the spread of Western economics during early modern times. Furthermore, this spread has a profound impact on China which is embodied in its features: it promotes the establishment of Chinese modern economics, provides appropriate examples for the modernization and evolution of Chinese society, and promotes transformation of the traditional economic system in China.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Premature Deindustrialisation in the Developing World
Dani Rodrik
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (1): 1-6.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0001-9
摘要   PDF (1015KB)

As developed economies have substituted away from manufacturing towards services, so too have developing countries—to an even greater extent. Such sectoral change may be premature for economies that never fully industrialised in the first place. This article presents evidence that countries with smaller manufacturing sectors substitute away from manufacturing to a larger extent, suggesting a trade channel through which falling international relative prices of manufacturing lead price-taking developing economies to substitute accordingly.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Private Label Positioning and Product Line
Stéphane Caprice
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (3): 480-513.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0021-3
摘要   PDF (779KB)

This article examines (i) how retailers position private label products, (ii) why private labels are sold in some product categories but not in others, and why some national brand products may have difficulty in accessing retailers’ shelves, (iii) why some private label products are positioned as ”premium” brands, and (iv) how consumers’ surplus and totalwelfare are affected by private labels. We find that private label positioning leads to less differentiation in product category, which structurally changes a retailer’s product line in return. Consumer welfare and total welfare are lower.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Who Defended Monetary Stability in a Specie Regime? Evidence from the Chinese History
Sheng Qian, LeminWu
Frontiers of Economics in China    2018, 13 (3): 397-435.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-007-018-0020-0
摘要   PDF (3345KB)

Despite the lack of political accountability, ancient autocracies maintained a level of monetary stability that rivals modern democracies. This paper hypothesizes that it is the threat of counterfeiting that has constrained currency debasement. Unwilling to share seigniorage with counterfeiters, who are active only if currency is debased, the government refrains from debasement unless in extreme fiscal situations. To document the facts, we build a database of historical Chinese copper coins that covers the period from the Qin dynasty (221 BC–207 BC) to the Republic of China. We also use the introduction of the steam press in late Qing China as a natural experiment to test the theory. The steam press produced coins of fine patterns that counterfeiters were unable to mimic. As the theory predicts, the removal of the threat of counterfeiting triggered the most serious debasement in the history of the Qing dynasty (1644–1912).

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Industry Interaction, Structure Transformation and High-Quality Economic Development in China
SONG Pei, LI Lin, BAI Xuejie
Frontiers of Economics in China    2023, 18 (4): 467-503.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-017-023-0028-5
摘要   PDF (1758KB)

Industry interaction is becoming an important approach to promoting high-quality economic development. In this paper, the multi-sector general equilibrium model is developed to clarify the theoretical mechanism among industry interaction, structure transformation, and high-quality economic development; the empirical tests are carried out based on the provincial panel data from 2000 to 2017; and the empowerment paths for digital technologies are explored to drive high-quality economic development. The findings are as follows. (1) The industry interaction can promote high-quality economic development in China on the whole, but it shows a significant imbalance and a healthy two-way promotion mode have not been formed. (2) The impact of industry interaction on high-quality economic development is significantly heterogeneous at the sector and regional levels. (3) The current unhealthy industry interaction may widen the productivity gap between manufacturing and service sectors, and transform China’s economic into service-oriented structure, thus leading the economic development to a vicious circle of “low efficiency to low-end servitization and further to lower efficiency,” and hindering the sustainability of high-quality economic development. (4) Digital technologies can break the development dilemma and achieve high-quality economic development by alleviating structural contradictions, boosting healthy industry interaction, and narrowing the productivity gap among sectors. The conclusions provide empirical evidence for the government to promote the integration of advanced manufacturing and modern service sectors and achieve high-quality economic development.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Legal Knowledge, Land Expropriation, and Agricultural Development in Rural China
Yi Che, Yan Zhang
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (1): 132-166.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0007-1
摘要   PDF (631KB)

By using household survey data, this paper examines the effect of legal knowledge, a proxy for farmers’ ability to protect their land, on agricultural development in rural China. The Ordinary Least Square (OLS) estimation results indicate that legal knowledge in a household raises agricultural production. Further, once the production effect of legal knowledge is controlled for, the objective measure of land expropriation has no production effect. These results survive for alternative measures of legal knowledge and subsample analysis. A two-stage least squares strategy further confirms that the effect of legal knowledge on farm production is causal. A preliminary channel analysis suggests that the impact of legal knowledge on farm production works mainly through farmyard manure investments and labor incentives.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Welfare Analysis of Tacit Coordination in the U.S. Airline Industry
Xiaolan Zhou
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (1): 66-93.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0004-0
摘要   PDF (267KB)

This paper studies airlines’ competitive behavior in the U.S. airline industry, focusing on 2014 data. I use a structural model to estimate demand and test several supply models, including noncooperative competition, perfect collusion, and tacit coordination. There are three different types of tacit coordination, formed by multimarket contact, common ownership, and codeshare agreement, respectively. I find that the model that fits the data best is a tacit coordination model with coalitions between airlines with at least 30% of their markets overlapped and using price rather than quantity as the strategic variable. I further analyze the consumer welfare loss, each carrier’s profit gains, and changes in market variables due to the tacit coordination.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Cooling China: The Weather Dependence of Air Conditioner Adoption
Maximilian Auffhammer
Frontiers of Economics in China    2014, 9 (1): 70-84.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-003-014-0005-5
摘要   PDF (1087KB)

One of the major adaptation mechanisms to climate change is increased demand for cooling via the air conditioning of indoor environments. China’s demand for air conditioners has displayed explosive growth since 1995. This paper provides estimates of the income and short run weather sensitivity of air conditioner adoption across urban areas for 29 Chinese provincial entities. We show that the adoption decision displays significant income and weather sensitivity in the short run, with adoption being higher the year following a hot summer.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Asset Securitization and Welfare Compensation for House Demolition on New-Type Urbanization in China
Fuxiang Wu, Wei Duan
Frontiers of Economics in China    2018, 13 (4): 602-634.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-007-018-0028-6
摘要   PDF (514KB)

In this paper we design a compensation mechanism for the relocated households in the process of New-Type Urbanization in China. Based on the theories of dynamic rent spatial separation, bid-rent and non-renewable resource exploitation, we give a theretical look at how the current compensation mechanism shapes the welfare of relocated households. Firstly, land rent growth has a spatial difference and the growth rate of the marginal location rent is much higher than that of the mature site. Secondly, there is a demolition championship contest under the sole static money compensation, which can easily lead to land urbanization faster than population urbanization. Thirdly, in the long run the welfare loss of the household is mainly due to the absence of a dynamic compensation mechanism. Furthermore, we design a dynamic compensation mechanism based on the establishment of an asset securitization capital pool, which could be an alternative scheme in the process of New-Type Urbanization.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Tuition Fees for Higher Education and Intergenerational Mobility in China
Yuanyuan Chen, Quanlin Liu, Kun Wu
Frontiers of Economics in China    2020, 15 (3): 396-432.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-011-020-0016-1
摘要   PDF (2216KB)

This paper studies the impact of an increase in higher education tuition on intergenerational mobility in China. We develop a theoretical model for the parental decision about the investment on education of children to illustrate the impact from the perspective of borrowing constraint. We consider the Chinese college tuition and subsidy reform around 1986 as a quasi-natural experiment for identifying the policy effect of the reform on intergenerational educational mobility by using the data from the census of 2000 and the China Family Panel Studies (CFPS). We find that an increase in the education burden induced by the reform of college tuition has reduced intergenerational educational mobility, and it is more noticeable in regions with a relatively higher increment in the tuition fee. Our results are robust with consideration of the co-residence bias, government investment in elementary education, and the higher education expansion.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
China’s Exports during the Global COVID-19 Pandemic
Yi Che, Weiqiang Liu, Yan Zhang, Lin Zhao
Frontiers of Economics in China    2020, 15 (4): 541-574.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-011-020-0023-7
摘要   PDF (1361KB)

The global COVID-19 pandemic caused various economic contraction in most countries, including all of China’s major trading partners. Using a difference-in-differences model, this study examines the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic on China’s monthly exports from January 2019 to May 2020. We find strong and robust evidence that China’s exports to countries at high risk from the pandemic experienced a larger decline than exports to low-risk countries after the onset of the pandemic, with the prices of exports increasing significantly. Furthermore, the results of a triple differences model show heterogeneous effects across different industries and goods. Chinese industries located upstream in the global value chain are more vulnerable than those located downstream. Industries with high labor and contract intensity (proxies for processing trade) experienced greater declines than other industries. Exports of goods with high import elasticity of substitution experienced higher prices and moderate volume losses due to the pandemic.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
The Trade-Off between Quantity and Quality in Family Fertility Decision: Evidence from China's Family Planning Policy
Shangao Wang, Xu Tian, Yingheng Zhou
Frontiers of Economics in China    2021, 16 (1): 67-104.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-013-021-0004-1
摘要   PDF (958KB)

Based on the Chinese General Social Survey 2006 and 2008 data, this paper assesses the influence of the family planning policy on the qualitative development of children using education attainment and individual income of only children versus children with siblings as parameters. Our results show the following: (1) only children are better-educated than their counterparts with siblings; (2) only children earn higher income in comparison to their counterparts with siblings; (3) the income and education gaps between girls with and without siblings are greater than those between boys; (4) the education gaps between only children and children with siblings are greater for those born in the 1970s, but the income difference between only children and children with siblings is only significant for those born in the 1980s; and (5) the income and education gaps between only children and children with siblings are higher in urban regions. Results indicate that families with only one child invest more resources in children’s quality under the family planning policy, which is consistent with the “quantity–quality trade-off” theory proposed by Gary Becker.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly
Cheng-Zhong Qin, Dandan Zhu, Shengping Zhang
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (3): 465-479.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0020-6
摘要   PDF (287KB)

A network approach is proposed to analyze the formation of cross-holdings and anti-competitive implications. Our approach is motivated by the bilateral arrangement of passive ownership between Microsoft and Apple in 1997. We provide a complete characterization of pairwise stable cross-holdings for a model of Cournot oligopoly with a homogeneous product. Our results strengthen the competitive implications of endogenous cross-holdings in Cournot oligopoly found in the literature.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
China’s Investments in Skills
James J. Heckman, Shuaizhang Feng
Frontiers of Economics in China    2018, 13 (4): 531-558.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-007-018-0025-5
摘要   PDF (8146KB)

This paper discusses the benefits of investment in skills in China. We highlight the achievements China has made over time in human capital investments and the new challenges that have emerged as the country develops. To fuel China’s further economic growth and social developments, it is essential to take a more holistic view on skill investments. We suggest policies that promote both economic efficiency and social mobility.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
An Overlapping-Generations Model of Firm Heterogeneity in Economic Development
Yu Chen, Haiwen Zhou
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (4): 660-676.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0027-5
摘要   PDF (323KB)

We study firm heterogeneity in economic development in an overlapping-generations general equilibrium model in which manufacturing firms engage in oligopolistic competition. Individuals differ in their productivities in the manufacturing sector and choose to become entrepreneurs or workers. The model is surprisingly tractable. In the steady state, an increase in the entry barrier in the manufacturing sector or an increase in the percentage of income spent on the agricultural good decreases the wage rate, but the level of output in the manufacturing sector does not necessarily decrease. An increase in the degree of patience of an individual increases the steady state wage rate and the capital stock. Even with increasing returns in manufacturing and constant returns in agriculture, neither the wage rate nor the output level in the manufacturing sector may increase with population size.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
How Does Digital Economy Drive China’s Rural Revitalization?
HE Leihua, WANG Feng, WANG Changming
Frontiers of Economics in China    2023, 18 (1): 118-144.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-017-023-0007-4
摘要   PDF (1381KB)

Digital economy, a new driving force for China’s economic development, creates a good opportunity for rural revitalization. This paper begins with a theoretical analysis of the impact of the digital economy on rural revitalization. Based on panel data from 30 provinces and cities in China from 2011 to 2018, as well as measurement-based digital economy development Index and rural revitalization index, the empirical test is conducted of the driving effect, mechanism and heterogeneity of digital economy on rural revitalization. Results show that the digital economy has a significant driving effect on rural revitalization, a conclusion that still holds even after taking into account endogenous problems and conducting a series of robustness tests. Technological innovation and human capital constitute the important mechanism for the digital economy to drive rural revitalization. Furthermore, the digital economy has a spatial spillover effect on rural revitalization, that is, it can promote rural development in neighboring areas. As regards various dimensions of rural revitalization, the digital economy can significantly promote ecological livability, civilized rural style, effective governance and prosperity. But its impact on the industrial boom is yet to appear. The western region enjoys more digital economy dividends in rural revitalization are more significant than central and eastern regions. Rural revitalization requires the government to deepen the integration of the digital economy and agriculture and implement a differentiated digital economy development strategy.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Regional and Sectoral Patterns and Determinants of Comparative Advantage in China
William Charles Sawyer, Kiril Tochkov, Wenting Yu
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (1): 7-36.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0002-6
摘要   PDF (1244KB)

China’s export performance is marked by large regional disparities which affect trade patterns at the national level. This paper uses data from input-output tables to estimate the comparative advantage of Chinese provinces in the three main economic sectors over the period 1992–2007. In contrast to existing studies, we include the services sector in the analysis and construct not only indices of revealed comparative advantage for overall trade, but also bilateral indices for interprovincial trade. The results indicate that West and Central China have a comparative advantage in agriculture/mining, coastal provinces in manufacturing, and metropolitan provinces in services. However, interprovincial trade exhibits a more complex pattern. Regression analysis identifies labor endowments as the key determinant of comparative advantage in total trade, while physical capital is the driving force in domestic trade. Human capital and government spending have a positive effect, whereas industrial loans and taxes, along with provincial trade barriers, impair comparative advantage.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Logic and Path of Combining Domestic Demand Expansion with Deepening of Supply-Side Structural Reform
ZHANG Peili
Frontiers of Economics in China    2023, 18 (4): 531-548.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-017-023-0030-6
摘要   PDF (759KB)

The fifth plenary session of the 19th Central Committee of the Communist Party of China (CPC) puts forward the organic combination of the implementation of the domestic demand expansion strategy with the deepening of supply-side structural reform, and scientifically reveals the internal logic of this organic combination and the realization paths, which is of great significance to the implementation of the new development concept and the construction of a new development pattern. First, this paper provides a theoretical explanation for the organic combination of the domestic demand expansion strategy with the supply-side structural reform by analyzing why the traditional policies for expanding domestic demand are ineffective in the new development stage of China. Second, this paper elaborates the internal logic of this organic combination from two aspects. (1) The base point of the domestic demand expansion strategy must be placed under the main line of the supply-side structural reform. (2) The two should be interconnected and are mutually reinforcing, so as to form a higher level of dynamic equilibrium in which the demand leads the supply and the supply creates the demand. Third, this paper analyzes the huge space for the organic combination of the domestic demand expansion strategy with the supply-side structural reform from the perspective of releasing consumption potential and creating new demand, and on that basis proposes the realization paths of their organic combination.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价
Does Health Insurance Coverage Influence Household Financial Portfolios? A Case Study in Urban China
Qin Zhou, Kisalaya Basu, Yan Yuan
Frontiers of Economics in China    2017, 12 (1): 94-112.   https://doi.org/10.3868/s060-006-017-0005-7
摘要   PDF (340KB)

Health insurance lowers the medical financial burden of the insured through a risk-sharing mechanism, and more importantly, reduces the motivation for precautionary saving. This paper explores the relationship between health insurance coverage and household financial portfolios. We choose 2002 urban China as a case study when the health insurance system had a problem of limited adverse selection. Using data from the 2002 Chinese Household Income Project Survey, we find that health insurance coverage influences households’ preference for financial assets, especially for the risky financial assets. These effects become more pronounced as the coverage rate of health insurance in the family increases. Our results are consistent with precautionary saving theory which suggests that future expenditure risk could affect household asset portfolios. Therefore, development of social security or a health insurance system could effectively promote the development of financial markets, especially riskier aspects of financial markets.

参考文献 | 相关文章 | 多维度评价